Wednesday, November 3, 2010

If Ben Bernanke is worried about income inequality, then he should stop quantitative easing.

Recently there’s been a lot of attention paid to the enormous wealth/income gap in the United States and to the disappearance of the middle class. In fact, the success of Republican/Tea Party members in this week’s elections was probably fueled at least in part by working (or unemployed) people’s sense that they are being left behind, while Wall Street “fat cats” are enjoying government bailouts and lavish pay packages. This political backlash is likely to manifest itself in many ways, one of which is increased scrutiny of the Federal Reserve and its behavior. Many newly elected representatives have been pushing to audit the Fed- or worse, abolish it- for a while, and they will undoubtedly take up those battles with gusto once they are sworn in. The question is, are they just peddling populist outrage?  Or, is there a legitimate reason to blame the Fed for income inequality and other distortions in the US economy?

Before digging into that question, some background is in order. First of all, here’s a brief primer on the problem of income inequality in the US. 

The best survey of income inequality in the US is on Slate’s web site. Timothy Noah’s series on the issue covers all (or almost all) the important bases and provides some background on the essential points, which are:

1) Income inequality in the U.S. has increased dramatically since 1979.  In 1979, 8.9% of total income went to the top 1% of earners, while in 2007 the top 1% took home 23.5% of the total.  Meanwhile, real wages for the average worker have essentially remained flat in the neighborhood of $20/hour since 1964 with minor fluctuations along the way.

Source: Institute for Policy Studies, Executive Excess 2009, p. 2.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Employment Statistics, Average Hourly Earnings in 1982 Dollars. Converted to 2008 dollars with CPI-U.
2) Income inequality is usually explained mostly by differences in educational attainment, with the gulf between income for earners with advanced degrees and earners with only high school diplomas widening recently to unprecedented levels.

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics
3) Income inequality is not generally believed to be the result of an upper class of “landed gentry” who simply live off their wealth while the rest of us toil.  Instead, the new rich derive most of their wealth from income they receive from work.  But, as we will see (and Noah doesn’t mention), it’s the specific nature of their compensation that reveals one of the key reasons the top 1% brings home so much more than the rest of us.

Another critical point about income inequality is that it is persistent and tends to be passed on from one generation to the next.  This runs directly counter to the idea that America is an ever-changing land of opportunity where rags-to-riches stories can come true.  In fact, as this article from the Economist points out, an individual’s prospects for social mobility in America are worse than they are in Europe, which is ironic, since -in the mind of the average American- Europe is a bastion of calcified Old World social structures that limit upward mobility.  This lack of mobility in the USA is presumably due to the fact that rich families tend to pass on educational and other advantages to their children, which they then use to land high-paying jobs, hence perpetuating the cycle.

So, what does all of this have to do with the Federal Reserve? Well, before I get to the ways in which the Federal Reserve supports and perpetuates this situation, I should point out that Ben Bernanke is well aware of it and has a sophisticated understanding of the issues, as this speech from 2007 demonstrates.   Bernanke clearly is concerned about income inequality, but what's interesting here is what he believes to be its causes.  Bernanke enumerates all the usual suspects- both for why skilled workers at the top make such outsized gains and for why people in the middle and below can’t seem to get ahead.  Differences in educational attainment along with the effects of technology and the “superstar effect” are all given as explanations for gains at the top, while the leveling effects of globalization, immigration, etc. are considered as reasons why the middle and below aren’t getting anywhere.

The one explanation conspicuously absent, however, is the increasing financialization of our economy and the enormous rise in asset values we have experienced since 1982, for which the Fed can take a lot of credit (no pun intended).  This, combined with the increasingly common use of stocks, stock options, and other asset-based forms of executive compensation is, in my opinion, the real source of income inequality.  And, since the Fed is largely responsible for fueling the asset inflation of the past 30 years by implementing ultra-low (and in some cases negative real) interest rates, quantitative easing, and other inflationary policies, it also bears a lot of responsibility for income inequality. Unfortunately, none of this is mentioned in Bernanke’s speech.

What exactly is the connection between asset inflation and income inequality?  It is, essentially, this: the richer you are, the more your compensation and net worth depends on the value of paper and other assets. For example, a quick look at any disclosure of CEO or top executive pay usually reveals that most of their income comes from stock option grants, deferred compensation tied to stocks, or some other form of asset-based compensation.  The CEO’s actual “salary” is usually only a small percentage of his or her overall compensation.  Remember, for example, that Warren Buffet’s salary is only $100,000 per year.  This chart from the AFL-CIO’s web site reveals that most CEO’s salary is only 1/9th their total compensation, while well over half their total pay comes directly from the sale of stocks and/or options. 

This fact explains how a CEO can make $10 million dollars annually even though his “salary” is only $1 million per year. It also implies that without constant asset inflation, the kind of out-sized gains we've seen for top earners would not be possible, since the majority of those gains come from the sale of paper assets.

Another connection between asset inflation and income inequality is the fact that over half of all stock market assets owned in America are held by the top 1% of earners, as the following chart shows.

Source: Author’s analysis of Arthur B. Kennickell, “Ponds and Streams: Wealth and Income in the U.S., 1989 to 2007,” Federal Reserve Board Working Paper, January 7, 2009, Figure A3a, p. 63. Does not include assets held in money market mutual funds or tax-deferred retirement accounts.
This contributes even more to the ultra-rich's sensitivity to asset prices.  Regular working people whose individual paper asset wealth may range from $10,000 to a few hundred thousand dollars aren't affected nearly as much by asset price swings as are the ultra-rich, who typically own millions (or billions) of dollars worth of stock.  Because of this, it’s no wonder that the rich will do anything to keep the asset-inflation party going, even if it means printing money or incurring federal debts that will ultimately be impossible to pay back.  After all, for the average person who lives mostly off his or her salary, a 50% decrease in the stock market hurts but it may only represent a loss of wealth equivalent to one year's salary. For an ultra rich person, however, a 50% drop in the stock market means the loss of many lifetime's worth of earnings from a typical salary- money that could never be earned back unless asset prices re-inflate.

Against this backdrop, one can see why the stock market meltdown of 2008 was so frightening to elites.  For a brief moment- before massive government and Federal Reserve intervention propped up asset prices- the ultra rich had no way of paying themselves and saw their net worth reduced by more than anyone would be able to make in many lifetimes of working for a salary or wage.  Any stocks, options, or other asset-based compensation they owned or were promised weren’t worth enough to convert into the kind of income they had become accustomed to.   Since then, of course, government bailouts have re-inflated asset markets (if not the real economy), and the game continues.

It’s interesting to note that during times of asset deflation, some curious things have happened to compensation for the average worker, who lives almost entirely off of wages and not from assets.  For example, in the following breakdown of average real wages from 1982 to the present one can see that during the market meltdown of 2008 the real wages of the average worker actually increased.  

Source: TheChartStore.com
This momentary increase was quickly obliterated, however, as the market bottomed in the beginning of 2009, and ever since then we’ve been back in a Fed- and debt-fueled rise in asset prices that has made the top 1% very rich and driven the average worker’s real wage back down to right where it was in 1964.

So, what’s the lesson here?  Essentially, the Fed and the Federal Government, by bailing out banks, printing and borrowing money, and supporting asset prices no matter what the cost, is perpetuating the income gap they claim to be trying to eliminate.  Avoiding the specter of deflation at all costs is the justification of all expansionary monetary policy, even though deflation (and especially asset deflation) may, in fact, be the only thing that corrects the imbalances in our economy and restores the average worker’s purchasing power and some sanity to our system.

When Bernanke announces today that he will print even more money to “save us from deflation,” he should know that he’s only perpetuating gross income inequality in America and, by extension, a system that all too many of us have realized is rotten.  It will be no surprise if he is taken to task for it in the near future by our newly elected representatives.

For more on the potentially tonic effects of deflation, see this thought provoking essay.

No comments:

Post a Comment